When a country has a lower opportunity cost of producing a product what type of advantage does this give a country?

People succeed in life by specializing at what they do best. If they do something where they do not have an advantage over others, then they will not be nearly as successful because of the competition. Likewise, for countries. A country can maximize its own wealth and the wealth of the world by specializing in what it does best, where it has the greatest advantages or the least opportunity costs. These are the products and services it should export. So, for instance, since Saudi Arabia has an abundance of oil, it exports oil, and since the United States has an abundance of fertile land, it exports agricultural products. On the other hand, Saudi Arabia is mostly desert, so it cannot grow enough food to feed its population, and the United States consumes more oil than what can be economically provided from its own resources. Both countries would be better off if Saudi Arabia traded oil for agricultural products and if the United States traded its agricultural products for oil.

A country has an absolute advantage in producing a good if it can either produce a product with fewer resources or with a lower cost of resources. The opportunity cost of a product or service is the difference in value between the value of what is produced with a given set of resources minus the maximum value that can be produced with those resources. A country has a comparative advantage in producing a good if it has a lower opportunity cost of producing that good compared to whatever else it could produce with its resources.

The differences between absolute and comparative advantage can easily be seen in a simple example. Take a model who makes $10,000 a day modeling but who is also very efficient at mowing her large yard around her mansion. If she cuts her grass herself, she can do it in one day. Or she can hire a lawn service that takes 2 days to mow the lawn and charges $400. Thus, the model has an absolute advantage in both working as a model and mowing her own lawn, but, she would, nonetheless, still hire the lawn service, because if she mowed her own lawn, she must give up a day of modeling, resulting in $10,000 less in earnings. By hiring the lawn service, she earns $10,000 a day as a model and pays the lawn service $400, for a net gain of $9,600. Hence, the $9,600 is her opportunity cost for mowing her own lawn. If the lawn service does not mow the model's lawn, then it will not get the $400 that it charges the model, but it will have time to mow other people's lawns for the same amount of money. Therefore, the lawn service's maximum opportunity cost of not mowing the model's lawn is only $400, which gives it a comparative advantage over the model.

Because countries differ in their absolute or comparative advantage in producing specific products or services, the world benefits by allowing free trade. However, trade is often restricted on the specious grounds of preserving jobs or because politically powerful people who will benefit from restricted trade want to increase their wealth at the expense of the public.

In the early 19th century, Corn Laws, which consisted of tariffs, subsidies, and restrictions on the trading of corn and other grains, were enacted by British Parliament so that the landowners in the House of Lords could increase their own wealth at the expense of the public, by discouraging imports and encouraging exports of grain, particularly corn.

In 1817, David Ricardo published Principles of Political Economy and Taxation in which he advanced the idea of absolute and comparative advantage by comparing the production of wine and cloth in England and Portugal. If, in England, it took the labor of 100 men working for 1 year to produce a given amount of cloth and 120 man-years to produce an equal value of wine, while, in Portugal, it took only 80 man-years to produce wine and 90 man-years to produce cloth of equivalent value, then Portugal has an absolute advantage in producing both wine and cloth because it can produce them with less labor than England. However, Portugal only has a comparative advantage in producing wine because the opportunity cost of producing cloth in England is less than the opportunity cost of producing cloth in Portugal. This is because England must sacrifice an extra 20 man-years to make wine while Portugal would only have to sacrifice 10 more man-years to make cloth. If England exported cloth for the wine, then it needs only the 100 man-years to create the cloth to exchange for the equivalent value of wine; if it produced its own wine, it would need 120 man-years. Likewise, for Portugal to make its own cloth, it must sacrifice 90 man-years, but by exchanging wine for cloth, it can receive the equivalent value of cloth for only 80 man-years. Hence, both England and Portugal benefit by trading wine for cloth.

Without trade, each country produces the goods that it consumes.

  • England
    • Cloth: 100 man-years
    • Wine: 120 man-years
    • Total: 220 man-years
  • Portugal
    • Cloth: 90 man-years
    • Wine: 80 man-years
    • Total 170 man-years

With trade, instead of producing both cloth and wine, England produces double the amount of cloth, exporting half of it for the equivalent amount of wine from Portugal. Portugal produces double the amount of wine, then exports half of it for the equivalent amount of cloth from England.

  • England, double the cloth: 200 man-years, saving 20 man-years over producing both products itself.
  • Portugal, double the wine: 160 man-years, saving 10 man-years over producing both products itself.
  • So the total savings of this international trade is 30 man-years. Each country is richer by engaging in international trade than it would be without trade.

(Here, it would seem that Portugal has the lower opportunity cost since it only has to sacrifice 10 man-years instead of 20. However, it only makes sense to compare opportunity costs using the same resources, meaning that an individual or a country can only compare what it can do with its own resources, since that individual or country is one of the resources. Hence, a country will only produce at its own lowest opportunity cost, and whether it will import or export will depend on those opportunity costs. So if Portugal, in the above example, can produce both wine and cloth at the cost of 80 man-years, then it will export both and import neither.)

Several years after the publication of his book, Ricardo became a member of Parliament where he presented his ideas as to why the Corn Laws should be repealed, arguing that specialization and free trade will benefit all trading partners, even those less efficient at producing.

Some economists make a distinction between natural and acquired comparative advantages. A natural comparative advantage exists within a country that has natural resources that are required to produce a product, while an acquired comparative advantage is the advantage gained by an individual or a country by spending a lot of time or resources producing a product. For instance, Saudi Arabia has a natural comparative advantage with its huge reserves of oil. (Saudi Arabia also has an absolute advantage in oil, since the cost of its extraction is less than elsewhere.) Since Saudi Arabia has few other resources, without trade, it would be extremely poor; because of trade, it is extremely wealthy. Japan, on the other hand, has few natural resources, but it has an acquired comparative advantage in its manufacturing and business know-how, which it has developed over the years.

Terms of Trade

The terms of trade is the ratio at which a country can exchange domestic products for imported products. If the imported costs of the products are less than the opportunity costs for the countries to produce the product themselves, then they will continue to trade the products. So, referring to the above example, Portugal would continue to import cloth from England as long as its opportunity cost of producing cloth itself is higher than the opportunity cost of producing wine that can be exported in exchange for the cloth.

Summary

To summarize, absolute advantage compares the nation's ability to produce a product or service compared to other nations, while comparative advantage compares one nation's ability to produce a product or service compared to the other products or services that it can produce and export. Most countries with an absolute advantage in a product also have a comparative advantage in that same product. For instance, Saudi Arabia has an absolute advantage in producing oil, because it can produce oil more cheaply than any other nation, but it also has a comparative advantage in oil production, because there is no other economic activity in Saudi Arabia that is as productive and profitable as producing oil.

Hence, absolute and comparative advantages determine what products or services nations import or export.

Syllabus: (You need to be able to)

  • Explain the theory of comparative advantage.
  • Describe the sources of comparative advantage, including the differences between countries in factor endowments and the levels of technology.
  • Draw a diagram to show comparative advantage.
  • Calculate opportunity costs from a set of data in order to identify comparative advantage.
  • Draw a diagram to illustrate comparative advantage from a set of data.

When a country has a lower opportunity cost of producing a product what type of advantage does this give a country?
    While Adam Smith (1723-1790) was raving about the insight that countries who produce goods more efficiently than others, are         better  off producing what they are good at, produce more than they need and trade the surplus for goods they are not efficient at     producing  (Absolute Advantage)...

                                                                ...David Ricardo (1772-1823) used this insight to bring a most amazing situation to light.         Countries will benefit from trade, not only when they have an absolute advantage, but also if they have a comparative advantage.

It would be always beneficial for two countries to trade if they have different relative costs (opportunity cost) of producing a good.

Why is this amazing? I hear you ask. The point is that countries are better off specialising and trading even if one of the countries is better (more efficient) at producing both (or all) goods. Now that is not so obvious. Thinking time: because on the face of it this does not make sense.

A country has a comparative advantage in producing a good, if it is able to produce the good at a lower opportunity cost (ie by sacrificing less production of other goods) than other countries.

You may wish to revise to revise PPC and Opportunity Cost because we are going to use these extensively for this theory. You will need to access the Microeconomic iText for this.

Comparative advantage theory

Start all models and theories with simplifying assumptions - to make it easier to understand the argument. The theory of comparative advantage is based on the following assumptions:

  • There are no trade restrictions
  • There are no transport costs
  • There are no exchange rates
  • It is a 2 good, 2 country world
These can be amended later once you have the basic understanding

You will see everything much more clearly if use graph paper and plot points properly, when following the reasoning below.

The point of what follows is that if countries do not specialise and trade the PPC is also the Consumption Possibility Curve ie the country cannot consume combinations of goods and services (ie Hardware and Software in the example below) that are beyond their respective PPC. However with specialisation and trade they can: Therefore as long as there are different opportunity costs of production (irrespective of which country is the more efficient - absolute advantage) both countries are better off specialising and trading.

Let´s do Economics!

There are two countries - Utopia and Happyland. These countries produce two products - Hardware and Software. According to the theory of comparative advantage each country should specialise in production of the good where it has a lower opportunity cost. You need to draw the PPCs for each country.

Before specialisation and trade situation and opportunity costs

1. Draw up a table: Before trade each country uses a half of its resources to produce hardware and another half to produce software.

Production and consumption Hardware (units) Software (units)
Utopia 100 500
Happyland 50 750
Total World 150 1250


2. Now construct the PPCs for both countries: Make sure you fully understand each step in the construction. Why are they a straight line? Actually what would be better is if you plot 2 separate diagrams (1 for Utopia and 1 for Happyland)

Figure 1 Production and consumption possibilities before trade

When a country has a lower opportunity cost of producing a product what type of advantage does this give a country?

3. Work out the opportunity costs of production: Try it before looking below.

Utopia:

To produce 200 units of Hardware the opportunity cost is (ie it cannot also have) 1000 units of Software - can you see why? Therefore producing 1 unit of Hardware `costs´ 5 units of Software:

1 Hardware = 5 Software

To produce more units of Software Utopia has to give up 1/5 Hardware (divide both sides by 5):

1 Software = 1/5 Hardware

Happyland:

To produce 1 more Hardware Happyland has to give up 15 units of Software:

1 Hardware = 15 Software

To produce more software Happyland has to give up 1/15 Hardware (Divide both sides by...?)

1 Software = 1/15 Hardware

4. Decide which country should specialise in which good. In conclusion, Utopia has a comparative advantage (lower opportunity cost) in production of Hardware and should specialise in production of Hardware.

Happyland has a comparative advantage (lower opportunity cost) in production of Software and should specialise in production of Software.

Specialisation

5. Construct a table to show the situation after production but before trade. The table below shows specialisation based on comparative advantage.


Hardware (units) Software (units)
Utopia (production) 200 0

Happyland

(production)

0 1500
Total production 200 1500

6. Specify suitable terms of trade: As each country produces only one good, they will have to trade to be able to consume some of the other good. The terms of trade must settle somewhere between the two opportunity cost ratios to ensure that both countries benefit. As we saw earlier:

In Utopia 1 Hardware = 5 Software and in

Happyland 1 Hardware = 15 Software, so make the terms of trade (the world price in real terms)

ToT: 1 Hardware = 10 Software

7. State an example trade: If Utopia decide they need 750 units of Software how much Hardware would they need to give up? Compare this with the `cost´of producing Software for themselves.

8. Construct a table to show the situation after trade: Utopia and Happyland will have the following amounts of Hardware and Software available for consumption (can you justify each number?):


Hardware (units) Software (units)

Utopia

(consumption)

125 750

Happyland

(consumption)

75 750
Total production 200 1500


9. Plot these points on your original 2 PPC diagrams - are they outside they original PPCs? Draw in the new Consumption Possibility Curves.

When a country has a lower opportunity cost of producing a product what type of advantage does this give a country?

10. Both countries are better off from specialisation and trade, because they can reach higher levels of consumption of both goods than was possible before specialisation. After trade they are both able to consume beyond their production possibility curves -no matter how many goods they decide to trade.

Ah you say - it is obvious from the original PPCs that Utopia should specialise in Hardware and Happyland. So how about doing this all again but this time the 2 countries are Paulinhastan and TwoMsasia?

Let´s do economics!

Using half their respective resources the countries can produce as follows. Now prove they are better off specialising even though Paulinhastan can produce more of both goods (Follow all the steps above but with these numbers)

Production and consumption Chilli burgers
Carrot cake
Paulinhastan
200
1000
TwoMsasia
50
750
Total World
250
1750

Limitations of comparative advantage theory

Syllabus: Discuss the real-world relevance and limitations of the theory of comparative advantage, considering factors including the assumptions on which it rests, and the costs and benefits of specialization (a full discussion must take into account arguments in favour and against free trade and protection.

In the real world what do you think New Zealand (Pop 4,565,185) specialises in? Does the USA (Pop 324,118,787)

produce these goods too? Can they produce more than NZ? Do they trade with NZ for these goods? Why?

Thinking time: Do the simplifying assumptions negate the principle of Comparative Advantage? How can you build into the model things like transport costs? Does the theory take into consideration political decisions?Research: Is Donald Trump a Free-trader? Collect some quotes to illustrate your view.